How big the government budget deficit actually is


Assignment:

ARBITRARINESS OF DEFINING DEFICITS AND SURPLUSES

Whether or not you have a deficit or surplus depends on what you count as a revenue and what you count as an expenditure. These decisions can make an enormous difference in whether you have a surplus or deficit. For example, consider the problem of a firm with annual revenues of $8,000 but no expenses except a $10,000 machine expected to last five years. Should the firm charge the $10,000 to this year's expenditures? Should it split the $10,000 evenly among the five years? Or should it use some other approach? Which method the firm chooses makes a big difference in whether its current budget will be in surplus or deficit.

Accounting is central to the debate about whether we should be concerned about a deficit. Say, for example, that the government promises to pay an individual $1,000 ten years from now. How should government treat that promise? Since the obligation is incurred now, should government count as a current expense an amount that, if saved, would allow it to pay that $1,000 later? Or should government not count the amount as an expenditure until it actually pays out the money? The Social Security system—a social insurance program that provides financial benefits to the elderly and disabled and to their eligible dependents and/or survivors—is based on promises to pay, and thus the accounting procedures used for Social Security play an important role in how big the government's budget deficit actually is.

MANY RIGHT DEFINITIONS

Many accounting questions must be answered before we can determine the size of a budget deficit. Some have no right or wrong answer. For others there are right or wrong answers that vary according to the wording of the question being asked. For still others, an economist's "right way" is an accountant's "wrong way." In short, there are many ways to measure expenditures and receipts, so there are many ways to measure surpluses and deficits. To say that there are many ways to measure deficits is not to say that all ways are correct. Pretending to have income that you don't have is wrong by all standards. Similarly, inconsistent accounting practices—such as measuring an income flow sometimes one way and sometimes another—are wrong. Standard accounting practices rule out a number of "creative" but improper approaches to measuring deficits. But even eliminating these, there remain numerous reasonable ways of defining deficits, which account for some of the debate.

NOMINAL AND REAL DEFICITS AND SURPLUSES

Another distinction that economists make when discussing the budget deficit and surplus picture is the real/nominal distinction. A nominal deficit is the deficit determined by looking at the difference between expenditures and receipts.1 It's what most people think of when they think of the budget deficit; it's the value that is generally reported. The real deficit is the nominal deficit adjusted for inflation. To understand this distinction it is important to recognize that inflation wipes out debt (accumulated deficits less accumulated surpluses). How much does it wipe out? Consider an example: If a country has a $2 trillion debt and inflation is 4 percent per year, the real value of all assets denominated in dollars is declining by 4 percent each year. If you had $100 and there's 4 percent inflation in a year, that $100 will be worth 4 percent less at the end of the year—the equivalent of $96 without inflation. By the same reasoning, when there's 4 percent inflation, the value of the debt is declining 4 percent each year. Four percent of $2 trillion is $80 billion, so with an outstanding debt of $2 trillion, 4 percent inflation will eliminate $80 billion of the debt each year.

The larger the debt and the larger the inflation, the more debt will be eliminated by inflation. For example, with 10 percent inflation and a $2 trillion debt, $200 billion of the debt will be eliminated by inflation each year. With 10 percent inflation and a $4 trillion debt, $400 billion of the debt would be eliminated. If inflation is wiping out debt, and the deficit is equal to the increases in debt from one year to the next, inflation also affects the deficit. Economists take this into account by differentiating nominal deficits from real deficits. We can calculate the real deficit by subtracting the decrease in the value of the government's total outstanding debts due to inflation.

DEBT MANAGEMENT

The U.S. government, through its Treasury Department, must continually refinance the bonds that are coming due by selling new bonds, as well as sell new bonds when running a deficit. This makes for a very active market in U.S. government bonds, and the interest rate paid on government bonds is a closely watched statistic in the economy. If the government runs a surplus, it can either retire some of its previously issued bonds by buying them back or simply not replace the previously issued bonds when they come due.

Solution Preview :

Prepared by a verified Expert
Macroeconomics: How big the government budget deficit actually is
Reference No:- TGS02091358

Now Priced at $25 (50% Discount)

Recommended (96%)

Rated (4.8/5)